Social norms and social sanctions are commonly mentioned as an element of the relational dimension of social capital. The other dimensions of social capital being the structural and cognitive dimensions. This conceptualisation, distinguishing between structural, relational, and cognitive dimensions, is one of the major approaches to social capital. This approach was systematically explored and elucidated by Nahapiet & Ghoshal (1998)[1] building on Granovetter’s (1992)[2] discussion of structural and relational embeddedness.
Social norms are actions regarded by a set of persons as proper or correct, or improper and incorrect
Social norms are socially enforceable expectations about what constitutes normal and appropriate action in a particular context[3]. Social norms “specify what actions are regarded by a set of persons as proper or correct, or improper and incorrect”[4]. Norms are the rules, beliefs, mores and habits which regulate behaviour[5].
Social norms serve as the foundations of maintenance of social order and are essential to the functioning of any social grouping including society. Norms are produced, reproduced, and reinforced through the normal conduct of everyday life[6]. Social norms differ from other norms, such as moral norms and legal norms, in that they are socially defined and enforced[7]. The importance of social norms and the informal social sanctions that support them can not be overstated since no human society could exist without them[8].
Types of social norms
Role of social sanctions
Social norms are supported by the expectation that violations will be punished
Social norms are supported by sanctions for violation of these norms. Norms rely on sanctions for their existence because, without punishment for violation, a norm is unlikely to exist[11]. For a social norm to be sustainable, it must provide suitable incentives and disincentives for its observation. This requires deviators from the desired behaviour to be sanctioned, and for a person who fails to sanction to in turn be sanctioned[12]. Norms are enforced due to the expectation that violations of the behavioural standard will be punished[8]. The expectation of sanctioning is essential to the maintenance of social norms.
Sanctioning may involve “second parties” who are directly affected by the normative deviance and may also involve “third parties” who are not directly affected[8]. It is these third-party sanctions that are considered the essence of social norms[3].
Social norms at different levels of analysis
Each social grouping develops its own distinct, although related, social norms
Social norms are complex multi-level phenomena that operate concurrently in multiple and overlapping social groupings at different levels of social organisation. From broad society-wide norms at the macro level, to norms that are more relevant to specific socio-cultural groupings at the meso level, to norms that develop in specific social groupings such as organisations, families, and interest groupings at the micro level. Norms are relevant at different levels of analysis simultaneously. Macro-level normative standards of action are broadly relevant and widely applicable, thus influencing the nature of the norms of social groupings. Norms form through social interaction in the context of a social grouping, within the context of macro-level norms[13].
Social norms and social capital
Social norms are a vital aspect of social capital
Social norms, and the informal sanctions that support them, have been described as one of the most important elements of social capital[14]. Norms are included in virtually all conceptualisations of social capital, perhaps with the exception of those utilising the most extreme forms of methodological individualism. Both Putnam (1995)[15] and Coleman (1990)[16] referred explicitly to the importance of social norms. Some scholars have claimed that informal sanctions are a major determinant of a society’s social capital because they are key to the enforcement of implicit agreements and social norms[17].
Schneider (2009)[18] claimed that all definitions of social capital contain three vital elements: networks, trust, and (shared) norms and culture. Norms are an important aspect of social capital because norms powerfully influence the nature of human action. Strong social capital is associated with norms that encourage prosocial actions, that discourages exploitation, and that create connection and cooperation for mutual benefit.
Coleman’s rational choice perspective
From Coleman’s rational choice perspective, social norms affect the costs and benefits that individuals consider when exercising choice because they are accompanied by potential rewards (for compliance) or punishments (for noncompliance). From this perspective “social norms are construed as outcome-oriented conditional constraints that enable the efficient coordination and realisation of individual preferences and self-interests within a social structure”[21]. This outcome orientation involves universalising assumptions by ignoring non-outcome-based action.
Putnam’s democratic perspective
From Putnam’s democratic or civic perspective, social norms do not function exclusively to facilitate the efficient realisation of individual preferences. They also foster reflexive social cooperation that enables the collective realisation of democratic ideals[22]. Social norms, therefore, facilitate the kinds of mutual obligations and cooperative actions that make democracy work[23]. This approach does not reduce social norms to rational norms as the rational choice approach does, but rather it inflates them to universally positive norms.
Bourdieu’s Marxian perspective
From Bourdieu’s Marxian perspective, social norms are primarily prereflective predisposes that shape individual and collective practices. Bourdieu’s foundational theory of human action is elaborated in his concept of habitus. For Bourdieu, habitus is the shared set of durable dispositions, perceptive schemes, and ingrained orientations that enables and limits individual and collective practices with a particular context[24]. This perspective avoids reductionism and inflation, however, tends to emphasise the non-voluntary predispositional reproduction of human action and association.
A balanced perspective
The conclusion that norms emerge from networks is accurate however says nothing about the nature of these norms and whether they are prosocial, productive, or encourage collaboration and collective action. In social capital literature, it is common to find claims that interactions and connections between people generate norms of trust and reciprocity[25]. This can be the outcome, and perhaps most often is the outcome, however, the outcome could instead be negative norms of distrust and self-interest. Clearly, there are other factors involved in influencing the nature of the outcome, but these are rarely acknowledged in the literature. This oversight may be in the interest of simplification of highly complex social processes.
Footnotes
- Nahapiet, J., & Ghoshal, S. (1998). Social capital, intellectual capital, and the organizational advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23(2), 242 ^
- Granovetter, M. (1992). Problems of explanation in economic sociology. In N. Nohria & R. Eccles (Eds.), Networks and organizations: Structure, form, and action (pp. 25–56). Harvard Business School Press ^
- Bendor, J., & Swistak, P. (2001). The Evolution of Norms. The American Journal of Sociology, 106(6), 1493–1545. ^
- Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Harvard University Press. p243 ^
- Spellerberg, A. (2001). Framework for Measurement of Social Capital in New Zealand. In Research and Analytical Report (Social Capital Programme) ^
- Cusack, T. (1999). Social Capital, Institutional Structures, and Democratic Performance: A Comparative Study of German Local Governments. European Journal of Political Research, 35(1), 1–34 ^
- Elster, J. (1989). Social Norms and Economic Theory. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(4), 99–117. ^
- Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2004). Third-party punishment and social norms. Evolution and Human Behavior, 25, 63–87 ^
- Cialdini, R B, & Trost, M. R. (1998). Social influence: social norms, conformity and compliance. In D. T. Gilbert, S. T. Fiske, & G. Lindzey (Eds.), The handbook of social psychology (Vol. 2, pp. 151–192). Mass: McGraw-Hill ^
- Cialdini, Robert B, Reno, R. R., & Kallgren, C. A. (1990). A Focus Theory of Normative Conduct: Recycling the Concept of Norms to Reduce Littering in Public Places. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 58(6), 1015–1026 ^
- Bendor, J., & Mookherjee, D. (1990). Norms, Third-Party Sanctions, and Cooperation. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 6(1), 33–63. ^
- Kandori, M. (1992). Social Norms and Community Enforcement. The Review of Economic Studies, 59(1), 63–80. ^
- Kitts, J. A. (2006). Collective Action, Rival Incentives, and the Emergence of Antisocial Norms. American Sociological Review, 71(2), 235–259. ^
- Fehr, E., & Gachter, S. (2000). Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159–181. ^
- Putnam, R. D. (1995). Bowling alone: America’s declining social capital. Journal of Democracy, 6(1), 65–78 ^
- Coleman, J. S. (1990). Foundations of social theory. Harvard University Press. ^
- Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2000). Informal Sanctions. In IEER Working Paper No. 59 ^
- Schneider, J. A. (2009). Organizational Social Capital and Nonprofits. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 38(4), 643–662 ^
- Granovetter, M. (2000). A Theoretical Agenda for Economic Sociology. ^
- López Castellano, F., García-Quero, F., & García-Carmona, M. (2019). Perspectives on human and social capital theories and the role of education: An approach from Mediterranean thought. Educational Philosophy and Theory, 51(1), 51–62. ^
- Lewandowski, J. D. (2012). Capitalising Sociability: Rethinking the Theory of Social Capital. In R. Edwards, J. Franklin, & J. Holland (Eds.), Assessing Social Capital: Concept, Policy and Practice (pp. 14–28). Cambridge Scholars Press. p16 ^
- Lewandowski, J. D. (2012). Capitalising Sociability: Rethinking the Theory of Social Capital. In R. Edwards, J. Franklin, & J. Holland (Eds.), Assessing Social Capital: Concept, Policy and Practice (pp. 14–28). Cambridge Scholars Press. ^
- Putnam, R. D., Leonardi, R., & Nanetti, R. Y. (1993). Making democracy work : civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton University Press ^
- Bourdieu, P. (1984). Distinction: A Social Critique of the Judgement of Taste. Routledge and Kagan Paul Ltd ^
- Buys, L., Rifai, A., Godber, A., Summerville, J., & Barnett, K. (2007). Building Community: Collaborative Individualism and the Challenge for Building Social Capital. In Australasian Journal of Regional Studies (Vol. 13, Issue 3). ^